"Think You Can Beat the Market? Eugene Fama Still Says You Can't" :D

Discussion in 'Technical Analysis' started by harrytrader, Oct 11, 2003.

  1. Soapbox time:

    Whenever I hear "beat the market" I cringe. It's a faulty paradigm. The market isn't an opponent that wins or loses. The market can't lose. You can lose if you fight the market. You can win if you go with the market. Just because you win doesn't mean the market loses, or because you lose doesn't mean the market wins. The market is.

    Now the question typically means, can you beat buy and hold. The answer depends on to what extent the trader goes with the market and doesn't fight it.
     
  2. funky

    funky

  3. Well said TriPack.

    Admitting that I have never read Fama and don't have any time or inclination to do so, it seems to me very reckless for an academical person to state that "something cannot be done", if this is indeed what he is saying.

    Under normal academic standards of "thru knowledge" you need to have the backing of a generally recognized principle to base such a negative exclusive statement on, e.g. stating that something would violate a law of thermodynamics or so. Because Fama does not know how to make money in the Chicago markets, it does not follow that other people could not. Maybe even some ET people do.

    nononsense
     
  4. What all this means is that a population of active traders will have a return no better (usually worse) than a population of buy and holders. Yes some active traders have much greater profit, but those profits are distributed by a random function. (A few people have most of the profits, most others scrape by or lose and you can't predict who will end up where from the outset.)

    This basically means the typical investor is better off not trading. This is does not look at the very small group of individuals who have an advantage due to market knowledge nor does is say such individuals don't exist. All the article says is that for the typical investor, the chances are that you won't find yourself in that small group of trading winners, so you are better off not active trading as an investment strategy.

    I'm supposing you can find the same phenomena outside of trading as well. If you look at any business activity- like the population of all people to took real estate classes, the population of people who took computer courses, the population of people who opened dry cleaning stores; you will get a very similar result. On average, none of those activities is a sure fire way to above normal profits and the chances are you won't find youself in the smaller group enjoying high profits.

    This is not to say that they're aren't programmers who've done very well for many years... and this doesn't say there aren't real estate people who are rich; it means that if you look at ALL participants (including those who left or lost money) these business activities (as a whole) aren't raking in higher than normal returns.
     
  5. maxpi

    maxpi

    Nobody is better equipped to ignore obvious things than the highly educated. I'm just really thankful to Fama for educating so many really intelligent and hard working people out of trading, it makes way for a not so smart and half motivated individual like myself.

     
  6. You're right that's what he means one must not misunderstood him. In fact it is not him who invented efficiency theory it is since the quants have taken over the finance field since the 1960s with Henri Markowitz whose article has been published 10 years sooner in the Journal of Finance - which has given him the Nobel Prize. Fama has the merit to refine efficiency definitions but his conclusion should be modulated. It is impossible to ignore this theory because it is like ignoring inertia law and it is the pilar of quantitative finance notably arbitrage theory. In fact it is so vast a subject and debates that all the academic researchs are focused on that. The problematic of Efficiency is crucial to understand. In fact it is by thinking about efficiency that I had been conducted to elaborate my model. And my conclusion is that market is efficient in some accepted sense by academics but it doesn't prevent some group of people to make money so that efficiency is still to be redefined according to me. What efficiency implies is that this group can only be a minority.

     
  7. Blatt must be a specimen of firm believer of Fama's conclusion - :D

    http://www.elitetrader.com/vb/showthread.php?s=&threadid=23134&perpage=6&pagenumber=8

    "History has clearly proven (along with high level research) that a purely technical approach does not beat the benchmarks over time. Why wont you (or anyone else selling those ridiculous trading systems) show proof that pure technical trading styles work over time? Let's say over the past 5-10 years. All you guys can do is criticize academic research and look down at the most successful fund managers in the world. How laughable!!!"

    I don't agree with Fama's conclusion, I only agree with fama's definitions which are incomplete and only some facettes of efficiency. In fact, and contrary to technical analysts opinions, technical analysis for me is not opposed to efficiency but contribute to it - that is to say my conclusion is completely at the opposite of both Fama's conclusion about technical analysis and technical analysts about efficiency :D
     
  8. i have no opinion on fama article but stuff like this is important because the majority of newbie traders i have met mistakenly believe they will transform their $10,000 account into $100,000 ... or even $1,000,000 in no time at all because of some assorted indicator or method or some other crap being peddled to them by the "trading predators".. people need a good dose of reality to the downside i think.
     
  9. Efficiency is indeed an epistemological problem of science see for example John L. casti's point of view in his paper "Confronting Science's Logical Limits " that one can also find in his book "Would be world " http://search.barnesandnoble.com/booksearch/isbnInquiry.asp?userid=35IMKTANQA&isbn=0471196932&itm=4

    Confronting Science's Logical Limits
    by John L.Casti (professor at the Technical University of Vienna and at the Santa Fe Institute like J. Doyne farmer).

    The mathematical models now used in many scientific fields may be fundamentally unable to answer certain questions about the real world. Yet there may be ways around these problems.

    To anyone infected with the idea that the human mind is unlimited in its capacity to answer questions, a tour of 20th-century mathematics must be rather disturbing. In 1931 Kurt Gödel set forth his incompleteness theorem, which established that no system of deductive inference can answer all questions about numbers. A few years later Alan M. Turing proved an equivalent assertion about computer programs, which states that there is no systematic way to determine whether a given program will ever halt when processing a set of data. More recently, Gregory J. Chaitin of IBM has found arithmetic propositions whose truth can never be established by following any deductive rules.


    These findings proscribe our ability to know in the world of mathematics and logic. Are there similar limits to our ability to answer questions about natural and human affairs? The first and perhaps most vexing task in confronting this issue is to settle what we mean by "scientific knowledge." To cut through this philosophical Gordian knot, let me adopt the perhaps moderately controversial position that a scientific way of answering a question takes the form of a set of rules, or program. We simply feed the question into the rules as input, turn the crank of logical deduction and wait for the answer to appear.
    Thinking of scientific knowledge as being generated by what amounts to a computer program raises the issue of computational intractability. The difficulty of solving the celebrated travelling salesman problem, which involves finding the shortest route connecting a large number of cities, is widely believed to increase exponentially as the number of destinations rises. For example pinpointing the best itinerary for a, salesman visiting 100 cities would require examining 100 x 99 x 98 x 97 x...x 1 possibilities-a task that would take even the fastest computer billions of years to complete.
    But such a computation is possible-at least in principle. Our focus is on questions for which there exists no program at all that can produce an answer. What would be needed for the world of physical phenomena to display the kind of logical unanswerability seen mathematics ? I contend that nature would have to be either inconsistent or incomplete, in the following senses. Consistency means that there are no true paradoxes in nature. In general, when we encounter what appears to be such a paradox-such as jets of gas that seemed to be ejected from quasars at faster than light speeds-subsequent investigation has provided a resolution. (The " super- luminal" jets turned out to be an optical illusion stemming from relativistic effects.)




    PROTEIN FOLDING PROBLEM considers how amino acids (left) folds up instantaneously into extraordinarily complex, three-dimensional protein (right) Biologists are no trying to unravel the biochemical "rules" that proteins follow in accomplishing this feat.




    Completeness of nature implies that a physical state cannot arise for no reason whatsoever; in short, there is a cause for every effect. Some analysts might object that quantum theory contradicts the claim that nature is consistent and complete. Actually, the equation governing the wave function of a quantum phenomenon provides a causal explanation for every observation (completeness) and is well defined at each instant in time (consistency ) . The notorious "paradoxes" of quantum mechanics arise because we insist on thinking of the quantum object as a classical one.

    A Triad of Riddles
    It is my belief that nature is both consistent and complete. On the other hand, science's dependence on mathematics and deduction hampers our ability to answer certain questions about the natural world. To bring this issue into sharper focus, let us look at three well-known problems from the areas of physics, biology and economics.

    Stability of the solar system. The most famous question of classical mechanics is the N-body problem. Broadly speaking, this problem looks at the behaviour of a number, N, of point-size masses moving in accordance with Newton's law of gravitational attraction. One version of the problem addresses whether two or more of these bodies will collide or whether we will acquire an arbitrarily high velocity in a finite time.In his 1988 doctoral dissertation,Zhihong ( Jeff ) Xia of Northwestern University showed how a single body moving back and forth between two binary systems (for a total of five masses) could approach an arbitrarily high velocity and be expelled from the system. This result, which was based on a special geometric configuration of the bodies, says nothing about the specific case of our solar system. But it does suggest that perhaps the solar system might not be stable .More important, the finding offers new tools with which to investigate the matter.

    Protein folding. The proteins making up every living organism formed as sequences of a large number of amino acids, strung out like beads on a necklace. Once the beads are put in the right sequence, the protein folds up rapidly to a highly specific three-dimensional structure that determines its function in the organism. It has been estimated that a supercomputer applying plausible rules for protein folding would need 10127 years to find the final folded form for even a very short sequence consisting of just 100 amino acids. In fact in 1993 Aviezri S. Fraenkel of the University of Pennsylvania showed that the mathematical formulation of the protein-folding problem is computationally "hard" in the same way that the travelling-salesman problem is hard. How does nature do it?

    Market efficiency. One of the pillars on which the classical academic theory of finance rests is the idea that markets are "efficient." That is,the market immediately processes all information affecting the price of a stock or commodity and incorporates it into the current price of the security. Consequently prices should move in an unpredictable,essentially random fashion discounting the effect of inflation. This, in turn, means that trading schemes based on any publicly available information, such as price histories, should be useless; there can be no scheme that performs better than the market as a whole over a significant interval. But actual markets do not seem to pay much attention to academic theory. The finance literature is filled with such market "anomalies" as the low price-earnings ratio effect, which states that the stocks of firms whose prices are low relative to their earnings consistently outperform the market overall.

    The Unreality of Mathematics
    Our examination of the three questions posed above has yielded what appear to be three answers: the solar system may not be stable, protein folding is computationally hard, and financial markets are probably not completely efficient. But what each of these putative "answers" has in common is that it involves a mathematical representation of the real-world question, not the question itself.
     
    #10     Oct 12, 2003