Bernankeism and the Destruction of the Dollar

Discussion in 'Wall St. News' started by just21, Nov 16, 2008.

  1. just21

    just21

  2. The only thing I don't think will be cheaper a month from now is gold itself.

    Therefore I would say that the prevention of the beginning of deflation has failed.
     
  3. just21

    just21

    How much does the gloomboomdoom report cost?
     
  4. just21

    just21

    Unconventional Measures:
    Bernankeism and the Destruction of the Dollar
    Robert Blumen, E-mail: robert@RobertBlumen.com.
    This article was originally given as a talk at the Burton S. Blumert conference on Gold, Freedom, and Peace, a benefit for
    LewRockwell.com.
    In 2002, then-Fed Governor
    Benjamin Bernanke burst into our
    monetary consciousness with his
    printing press speech. His fine work
    earned him the honorary title
    “helicopter commander”. While
    largely a background figure since
    then, his recent appointment to
    succeed Alan Greenspan as Fed chair
    makes this an ideal time to review
    Dr. Bernanke’s views on monetary
    policy, and to speculate about what
    his chairmanship will bring.
    Since the Fed emerged from its
    near-death experience in the 1970s,
    it has largely — and misleadingly —
    been identified with the label
    “inflation fighting”. Against this
    backdrop, it is notable that Dr.
    Bernanke’s research and speaking
    have dealt predominantly with the
    subject of deflation.
    While his infamous address before
    the National Economists Club, titled
    “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t
    Happen Here” (2002), has been
    endlessly reported and debated, more
    revealing and less well known are Dr.
    Bernanke’s many speeches on
    deflation between 1999 and 2004,
    and a series of research papers on the
    same subject produced by the then-
    Fed governor and a number of his
    colleagues.
    I have identified 14 papers and
    speeches dealing with deflation (see
    the references section), seven by Dr.
    Bernanke and seven by other Fed
    governors and staff economists. These
    materials are all available for public
    download on the Fed’s website. To
    steal a line from columnist Dave
    Barry, “I’m not making this up.”
    A review of the most important
    points from these sources outlines a
    consistent point of view on deflation.
    While Governor Bernanke is not the
    only member of the anti-deflation
    wing at the Fed, the chair-in-waiting
    has emerged as the most prominent
    advocate of this new agenda. His
    leadership merits the name
    “Bernankeism” for this policy
    program.
    Upon reading the source
    materials, three main tenets of
    Bernankeism emerge. I will describe
    them and illustrate with examples in
    the Fed’s own words. The three are:
    prevention is better than cure, learn
    the lessons of history, and the
    possibility of “unconventional
    measures”.
    PREVENTION IS BETTER
    THAN A CURE
    The first principle of Bernankeism is
    that it is better to prevent deflation
    than to attempt a cure after the
    disease has set in.
    The basis of the Bernanke school’s
    thinking on deflation is the standard
    (mainstream) macroeconomic view
    that consumer spending (not saving)
    drives economic activity, and that
    insufficient consumer spending is the
    cause of recessions. According to this
    view, when recession strikes,
    inflation is called for.
    Inflation works in three ways. One,
    by lowering real prices when nominal
    prices are for some reason “stuck” at
    above-market-clearing levels; and two,
    by threatening a continued erosion in
    the purchasing power of cash,
    inflation motivates anti-social cash
    hoarders to spend, thus providing the
    missing stimulant to economic
    activity. A third is through so-called
    “wealth effects”: when asset prices
    inflate, people misperceive the
    inflation as true wealth and then
    increase their spending.
    Deflation is so dangerous,
    according to Dr. Bernanke, because it
    is a self-reinforcing process that is
    very difficult to reverse once it has
    begun. They start from the true
    observation that when people spend
    less, prices fall. They then reason that
    when prices fall, people become
    increasingly reluctant to spend (and
    businesses to invest) because they
    anticipate that prices will continue to
    fall. People start to hoard cash,
    planning to buy tomorrow when
    things are cheaper. The less people
    spend, the more prices fall, and the
    more that people hoard. In the grip of
    cash hoarding, according to
    Bernankeism, the entire economy
    would spiral down, as all spending
    ground to a halt.
    For an example of this view, I will
    cite the research paper titled
    “Monetary Policy and Price Stability”
    (1999) (by Fed research staffers):
    If economic activity is weak or
    contracting and interest rates hit
    the zero bound, a dangerous
    dynamic can be set in motion.
    Falling inflation, or even
    escalating deflation, would
    increase real rates of interest. As
    this depresses aggregate demand
    further, downward pressures on
    prices would raise real interest
    rates further: The economy would
    potentially face a downward
    deflationary spiral.
    Governor Bernanke and his
    accomplices are obsessed with
    something known as “the zero bound
    problem”. Eight of the 14 papers and
    speeches that I examined deal with
    this problem either as their main
    point or in passing.
    The zero bound comes about as
    follows. The Fed commissars concern
    themselves largely with controlling a
    single rate of interest, the Fed Funds
    rate. This rate can be lowered only to
    near zero, but not to zero or below,
    because no one would buy a bond
    that had a zero or negative yield; they
    would hold cash instead. This poses a
    problem for the central banker
    determined to inflate: if the Fed
     
  5. just21

    just21

    Funds rate hit zero (or near-zero, as it
    did with Japan), inflation cannot be
    accelerated by cutting the Fed Funds
    rate. In these circumstances, the Fed’s
    inflation program would be frustrated.
    For this reason, Bernankeism
    advises the central bank to avoid the
    zero bound problem by creating a
    constant state of pleasant and benign
    inflation of around 2–3%. This will
    keep the economy a safe distance
    away from the dangerous precipice
    beyond which lies deflation, and
    gives the Fed room to cut rates.
    For an example of their thinking,
    I cite a speech titled “An Unwelcome
    Fall in Inflation” (2003). Dr.
    Bernanke states:
    I hope we can agree that a
    substantial fall in inflation at this
    stage has the potential to interfere
    with the ongoing U.S. recovery,
    and that in conceivable —
    though remote — circumstances,
    a serious deflation could do
    significant economic harm. Thus,
    avoiding a further substantial fall
    in inflation should be a priority of
    monetary policy. To my mind, the
    central import of the May 6
    statement is that the Fed stands
    ready and able to resist further
    declines in inflation; and — if
    inflation does fall further — to
    ensure that the decline does not
    impede the recovery in output
    and employment.
    LESSONS LEARNED FROM
    HISTORY
    The second principle of Bernankeism
    is that central bankers must heed the
    lessons of history. According to the
    papers and speeches, the Fed’s fear of
    deflation is based on the two great
    20th-century failures of central banks
    to inflate: America’s Great
    Depression and the Case of Japan in
    the 1990s.
    Dr. Bernanke accepts Milton
    Friedman’s theory of the Great
    Depression. In the Freidman view, a
    contraction of the money supply
    brought about by loan defaults and
    then bank failures turned what would
    have been an ordinary recession into
    the Great Depression. This
    catastrophe could have been avoided
    had the Fed inflated sufficiently. The
    Friedmanites depict a Federal Reserve
    System ideologically paralysed by the
    so-called liquidationists.
    A recent front-page story in The
    Wall Street Journal delved further into
    the pending chairman’s views on the
    Depression.
    For decades, many economists and
    policy makers thought the
    Depression was the inevitable
    consequence of excess
    investment, flawed corporate
    governance and speculation in the
    1920s, culminating in the 1929
    stock-market crash. That view
    was reinforced by John Kenneth
    Galbraith’s 1955 book The Great
    Crash, 1929.
    Milton Friedman and Anna
    Jacobson Schwartz upended that
    view in 1963. In A Monetary
    History of the United States, 1867–
    1960, they argued that the
    Depression was far from inevitable,
    but brought about by an “inept”
    Federal Reserve. First, they said,
    the Fed foolishly raised interest
    rates in 1928 to end speculation on
    Wall Street, causing a recession
    the next year that precipitated the
    crash. Then, it let thousands of
    banks fail and the money supply
    shrink. In part, it thought weak
    banks should be allowed to fail. It
    also feared that lower interest rates
    might lead foreigners to dump
    dollars, straining the currency’s
    link to gold.
    Our next Fed chair, in a speech
    given in honour of Milton Friedman
    (2002), expressed contrition on
    behalf of central bankers everywhere
    in saying, “I would like to say to
    Milton and Rose: Regarding the
    Great Depression. You’re right, we
    [the Fed] did it [caused the
    Depression]. We’re very sorry. But
    thanks to you [Friedman], we won’t
    do it again.” The Fed has learned its
    lesson.
    The Depression has also shown
    that central banks should adopt an
    “asymmetrical” attitude toward asset
    bubbles. Smile on the way up, and
    then, try to reinflate them on the way
    down. From the same WSJ article.
    … addressing the Fed’s Jackson
    Hole, Wyo., conference in 1999,
    Mr. Bernanke and Mr. Gertler
    said the Fed should raise rates if
    rising asset prices fuel inflation,
    but not to prick a bubble. “A
    bubble, once pricked, can easily
    degenerate into a panic,” they
    said. When the bubble eventually
    collapses on its own, the Fed
    should cut interest rates to limit
    the damage to the financial
    system and the broad economy.
    and:
    The Depression, he contends, has
    taught the importance of avoiding
    both deflation — that is, generally
    falling prices — and inflation. It
    has also shown the threat that
    falling asset prices — such as,
    potentially, in housing — and
    weakened banks can pose. Most
    important, it shows the damage
    the Fed can do when it follows
    wrong-headed ideas.
    The failure of Japan’s central bank
    to inflate its economy out of the mess
    following the bursting of the 1980s’
    stock and real estate bubbles comes
    in a close second to the Depression in
    the Bernanke manual for deflation
    fighters. Four of the 14 Fed speeches
    deal mostly or entirely with Japan’s
    attempt to inflate its way out of a
    series of recessions that followed their
    bust. Despite successive Keynesianstimulus
    public-works programs (that
    have nearly paved the entire island of
    Japan into a parking lot), several
    years of a near-zero short-term
    interest rate, and a massive program
    of foreign exchange intervention that
    has left the BOJ holding hundreds of
    billions of dollars worth of US
    Treasuries, the BOJ has been unable
    to generate much inflation at all.
    To cite one of many examples, in
    a speech titled “Preventing Deflation:
    Lessons from Japan’s Experience in
    the 1990s” (2002) (a paper by four
    Fed staff economists) we read:
    We conclude that Japan’s
    sustained deflationary slump was
    very much unanticipated by
    Japanese policymakers and