How the Central Bank Fed affects our lives

Discussion in 'Economics' started by zdreg, May 19, 2025 at 3:31 PM.

  1. zdreg

    zdreg

     
    EdgeHunter and S2007S like this.
  2. Can we have cliff notes? I am not wasting 40 minutes of my life on this :)
     
    maxinger likes this.
  3. YouTube and social media is toxic to your mind, personality, peace, aura, life essence. Learn to abstain from all the random bullshit, nonsense, distractions and hype in modern society, culture. If you want to be a purer human being.
     
    ElCubano and maxinger like this.
  4. SunTrader

    SunTrader

  5. maxinger

    maxinger

    upload_2025-5-20_5-57-47.png


    No one is going to watch it.

    Even the OP didn't watch it.
    The video must be fool of BS and that's why OP didn't write the cliff notes.
     
  6. S2007S

    S2007S



    I'm going to watch it....
     
  7. S2007S

    S2007S

    Just watched the first few minutes...
    I'll be finishing this in its entirety tonight.

    Thank you zdreg for posting this.....
     
  8. maxinger

    maxinger

    You must be the most patient man in the world.

    But then, there are a billion more videos for you to watch it.
    Have fun watching those.
     
    MarkBrown likes this.
  9. SunTrader

    SunTrader

    Here we go again:-

    (THEDAILYUPSIDE)

    BANKING
    Banks Thrill to Potential Softening of Post-Crisis Capital Requirements
    2008 was a different time. Flo Rida's "Low” was Billboard’s top song, Christopher Nolan’s The Dark Knight was the highest-grossing movie, and a deregulated Wall Street was in meltdown. While the world is still flush with Batman content, Flo Rida hasn’t had a hit in a decade and Wall Street has had a couple of good years, even if it’s mired in a haze of tariff uncertainty at the moment.

    But some parts of the "before time" may be making a comeback: The Financial Times, citing multiple sources, reported last week that the US is poised to slash capital requirements imposed on banks in the wake of the 2008 crash. The banking industry, unsurprisingly, was already quite optimistic about a potential change

    Treasure for the Treasury Market
    The focal point is the so-called supplementary leverage ratio, a rule that requires banks to hold a certain percentage of their deposits in liquid assets. Introduced by the US in 2014 as part of the Basel III international banking regulations, it is intended to make sure lenders have enough cushion to cover their risks and endure financial shocks like the 2008 crisis.

    The baseline ratio is 3%, but for big banks deemed systemically important (code for "too big to fail"), it's 5%. Treasury Secretary Scott Bessent essentially said changes are coming earlier this month, when he told Congress it was a "high priority" for the Federal Reserve, Federal Deposit Insurance Corp. and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the three regulators that oversee the rule. Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell also told lawmakers in February that reducing the SLR is something he expects to “get done.” The FT, meanwhile,reported that the ratio is now poised to be reduced in a matter of months, something Wall Street has argued would be a boon to the $29 trillion Treasury market:

    • Bank lobbying groups have said the SLR prevents lenders from being more active intermediaries in the Treasury market. Powell signaled his agreement in February: “The amount of Treasurys has grown much faster than the intermediation capacity has grown, and one obvious thing to do is to lower, is to reduce the effective leverage ratio, the bindingness of it.”
    • Bloomberg’s editorial board was skeptical of a change when Bessent floated it last month, calling it a "questionable idea" to "let banks load up on federal debt" at a time when "banks are overleveraged and Treasurys aren't entirely safe." In the latter case, it cited the shock waves that the Trump administration’s tariff policies have sent through bond markets.
    The Bloomberg editorial board suggested the US could improve the standing of its sovereign debt by "making an effort to get government finances under control" and argued changing the SLR would merely weaken banks. To that point, Moody’s downgraded US sovereign debt on Friday, citing the federal debt and deficits — it was the last major credit rating agency to maintain a top rating for the US.

    [​IMG] An Alternate Approach: Rather than cutting the SLR, regulators have considered excluding Treasurys and other assets deemed low risk from the calculation — something that was temporarily enacted during the pandemic. The FT noted that Autonomous Research estimated reviving the exemption would free up $2 trillion of balance sheet capacity for the big US banks.

    Written by Sean Craig
     
  10. SunTrader

    SunTrader

    [​IMG]


    Liberty Street Economics
    « The College Economy: Educational Differences in Labor Market Outcomes | Main

    May 20, 2025
    Why Does the U.S. Always Run a Trade Deficit?
    Thomas Klitgaard

    [​IMG]
    The obvious answer to the question of why the United States runs a trade deficit is that its export sales have not kept up with its demand for imports. A less obvious answer is that the imbalance reflects a macroeconomic phenomenon. Using national accounting, one can show deficits are also due to a persistent shortfall in domestic saving that requires funds from abroad to finance domestic investment spending. Reducing the trade imbalance therefore requires both more exports relative to imports and a narrowing of the gap between saving and investment spending.

    Grounded by Accounting
    To give some intuition for why the trade deficit is equal to the gap between saving and investment spending, assume the U.S. economy is closed to the rest of the world. That is, there are no imports or exports. Spending is either on the consumption of goods and services or investment spending on equipment, structures, and intellectual property products. Income is allocated to either consumption or to saving by households, businesses, and government. In a closed economy, spending equals income—that is, the sum of consumption and saving equals the sum of consumption and investment spending.

    Spending (Consumption + Investment Spending) =
    Income (Consumption + Saving)

    Because consumption drops out on both sides of the equation, investment spending equals domestic saving in the economy. This makes sense: the funds available to invest in productive projects have to come from domestic savers.

    Opening up the economy to external borrowing or lending allows domestic saving and investment spending to diverge. In the case of the United States, the economy borrows from the rest of the world because domestic saving is insufficient to fully finance investment spending.

    Investment Spending = Domestic Saving + Foreign Saving (through net financial inflows)

    So how is the saving gap connected to international trade? If imports and exports are equal, then the revenue earned from exports matches the spending on imports. If export revenues don’t cover imports, then a country has to offer up IOUs. These come in the form of foreign funds buying domestic assets instead of U.S. exports.

    Imports = Exports + Net sales of U.S. assets (net financial inflows)

    Note that these inflows are fungible, so they might initially be used to buy U.S. government bonds, but that frees up other funds to finance the building of homes and the outfitting of factories. (There are financial flows out of the United States to buy foreign assets, so the net of these flows equals U.S. borrowing.)

    The key insight is that the amount of U.S. borrowing is the same whether viewed as the difference between saving and investment spending or between exports and imports. It is what it is, and it has to be the same value in both calculations, diverging only because of statistical discrepancies.

    What the Data Say
    The chart below shows gross U.S. saving and investment spending since 2000, with both calculated as shares of nominal GDP to make the values comparable across time. From 2000 to 2007, the gap widened as investment spending as a share of GDP dipped and then recovered while the saving share failed to fully recover. The gap contracted with the global financial crisis in 2008 as investment spending fell by more than saving, and then narrowed further as saving staged a stronger recovery. More recently, saving dipped during the pandemic and has stayed low in the aftermath while investment spending as a share of GDP has been stable over the whole period.


    Saving Has Been Persistently Less Than Investment Spending

    Share of GDP (percent)

    2000200420082012201620202024051015202530Investment spendingSaving
    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
    Note: The saving gap differs from the current account balance because of statistical discrepancies.

    The chart below breaks out household, business, and government saving. (Saving is the difference between income and expenses, with expenses not including investment spending.) Business saving is the most stable, dropping with the financial crisis and rebounding to above its pre-crisis level, then staying near there ever since. Household saving as a share of GDP held up well during the financial crisis, then moved above its pre-crisis level until the pandemic, when it jumped as a result of government transfers and restrictions on consumer spending. It has since stayed below its pre-pandemic level, in part due to consumers spending down the unusually high amount of saving accumulated in the 2020-21 period. Notice that total saving is more stable than the individual components because of offsetting movements, particularly between household and government saving.


    Household and Government Saving Often Offset Each Other

    Share of GDP (percent)

    2000200420082012201620202024-15-10-505101520BusinessHouseholdGovernment
    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

    Macro versus Micro
    The saving gap framework helps clarify what trade policies can and can’t do. For example, a free-trade agreement encourages exports, and an industrial policy can foster a re-shoring of production to replace imports. Such policies influence the size and composition of cross-border trade, but the difference between imports and exports is only affected if these policies also change the gap between domestic saving and investment spending.

    The chart below illustrates how focusing on imports and exports can be misleading. In 2011, the U.S. trade deficit in petroleum products reached $330 billion. The overall trade deficit, measured by the current account, was $455 billion, so oil accounted for roughly 75 percent of the entire deficit. Surely the deficit would shrink if the United States wasn’t dependent on imported oil. As it turned out, a dramatic increase in domestic oil output caused the oil deficit to disappear by 2019. Nevertheless, the overall deficit grew to $441 billion, consistent with a wider saving gap.


    The Overall Trade Balance Is Not Tied to Specific Items

    Share of GDP (percent)

    2000200420082012201620202024-6-5-4-3-2-101OilTotal
    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
    Notes: Oil is petroleum and petroleum products. Total is the current account balance.

    Debating Trade Deficits
    An argument against running a trade deficit is that it requires U.S. assets that would otherwise have been held domestically to be sold to foreign investors. As a consequence, income generated by these assets flows out of the country instead of going to domestic investors.

    The saving gap perspective tells a contrary story. Investment spending would have been lower if not for the United States being able to borrow from the rest of the world. One can argue that this funding raised the economy’s productive capacity from what it would have been otherwise.

    Finally, achieving the goal of a smaller trade deficit will likely be painful, since it requires a recalibration of domestic savings and investment. Studies have found that episodes of substantial reductions in trade deficits were typically facilitated initially by lower investment spending and subsequently through higher saving, as was the case with the improvement in the U.S. current account during the 2008 recession and its aftermath.

    [​IMG]
    Thomas Klitgaard is an economic policy advisor in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

    https://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2025/05/why-does-the-u-s-always-run-a-trade-deficit/
     
    semperfrosty and zdreg like this.